Fed’s Bullard Calls For ‘Organized Shutdown’ Of US Economy Until July 1

By James Bullard, President and CEO, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, March 23, 2020

Introduction

The coronavirus has the potential to create catastrophic health outcomes in the U.S.2 In order to mitigate this, public health officials have recommended a variety of social-distancing policies to slow the spread of the virus. In addition, social interaction has declined dramatically due to voluntary withdrawal by individuals, corporate work-from-home policies and government restrictions.

These actions and policies have had the effect of engineering a controlledpartial and temporary shutdown of certain sectors of the U.S. economy. The productive capacity of the U.S. economy is fundamentally strong and resilient–nevertheless, this organized “throttling down” radically changes the way we need to think about and gauge the health of the U.S. economy in the near term.3 The U.S. economy will, by design, behave very differently than what is conventionally assumed in ordinary times–so differently, in fact, that ordinary business cycle analysis will be ineffective and cease to make sense. The goals of macroeconomic policy will need to be very different, in some ways the opposite of what we would normally try to accomplish.

A National Pandemic Adjustment Period

I begin by recommending that the President and Congress declare a “National Pandemic Adjustment Period” (NPAP), providing a natural focal point for the expectations of policymakers and Americans at large concerning what is happening. The NPAP would initially extend from now until the end of the second quarter of 2020, and would be flexible enough to be shortened or extended as necessary depending on how the virus progresses. Special policies would be in effect for the duration of the NPAP, and the dates that these special policies would expire could be tied to the end date of the NPAP.

There are three broad goals to be accomplished during the NPAP.

1. Greatly Reducing Economic Activity

The first goal during the NPAP is to intentionally reduce (reduce!) economic activity in order to meet public health objectives. Production is to be carried out only if (1) the good or service is deemed “essential,” or (2) the good or service can be produced in a way that does not risk transmission of the virus. If production is reduced in this way, this will be considered success during the NPAP.

My rough initial estimate of the level of U.S. real GDP (and hence national income) that meets this public health objective is up to 50% of normal production. In other words, we need to throttle back the U.S. economy to produce at only half its normal pace.4

It would be inappropriate to characterize that outcome as a recession because it is undertaken intentionally to meet public health objectives. In particular, it is inappropriate to argue for “economic stimulus” intending to ramp up production or create new demand in this situation, as that would work at cross-purposes with the goal of reducing the level of economic activity in order to meet public health objectives. A better concept is that we should strive to “keep everybody whole” during the NPAP, as described in more detail below.5

A normal quarter of production of goods and services in the U.S. recently, in very round numbers, is about $5 trillion. Producing only half would mean that national income is cut to about $2.5 trillion during the second quarter of 2020 when the NPAP is in effect. This is a quarter-over-quarter drop of 50%, well outside historical experience in the U.S.

This outcome is expected and temporary and simply reflects the large investment in public health that will be made in the U.S. This change in magnitude is something to be expected and to prepare for, reinforcing the point that standard business cycle tracking serves little useful purpose in the near term.6 Data during the NPAP will be coming from a special situation.

2. Keeping Households and Firms Whole

The second goal of policymakers is to prevent destruction of livelihoods and firms during the NPAP. This planned, organized partial shutdown will clearly have very uneven effects across households and firms during the NPAP. Some types of businesses are closed down completely, while other types continue to operate.

On the household income side, the goal is to keep households whole. We already have government income maintenance programs, popularly known as unemployment insurance (UI). I recommend using these programs extensively and changing the label on these programs to “pandemic insurance” (PI) during the NPAP to more appropriately reflect what is happening. Heavy use of this facility by individuals–to the extent that it helps to maintain laid-off workers’ income–should be used as a metric of policy success during the second quarter. Heavy use would mean that the government is making the proper transfers to those who have been disrupted by the health objectives of the country. To help accomplish this, benefit replacement rates could be increased substantially from the current average rate in the U.S. of about 45% to a value close to or equal to 100%.

Moreover, every state has a well-established UI system with rules already in place. Stress will be placed on these systems as the number of claims made in the upcoming weeks may be unprecedented; nonetheless, this facility is much better than the alternative of trying to set up a new system on the fly.

My initial estimate of the level of pandemic insurance that may be appropriate during the NPAP period is 30%.7 That is, up to 30% of the workforce could be using this program as part of an optimal policy response to the pandemic.

The intentional, partial reduction in production means capital will also be unemployed during the NPAP. Conceptually, factories will shut down for a period of time and then reopen once the pandemic has passed with the capital intact. National policy, therefore, needs to make the owners of capital whole during this period. Most proposals in this area under consideration in Congress provide loans to businesses, large and small, to tide businesses over until they can start up again after the NPAP.

3. Paying for the Pandemic Response

The third goal is to pay for the pandemic response. If national income falls by 50% during the NPAP, households will not be able to maintain their normal lifestyles. In other words, consumption is likely to be much lower than normal for most households during the NPAP. Most of this reduction will come as a result of the health objectives themselves–many avenues for ordinary consumption will simply be closed, and in addition people are being asked to remain in their homes. To a large extent, national income will be down, but national consumption will be down in tandem with national income. This is the nature of “hunkering down.”8 The federal government is certainly borrowing, but most of this is oriented toward maintaining market functioning and extending loans to businesses to tide them over until full-speed production can once again resume.

Summary

Just as incoming macroeconomic data should be interpreted in light of the unprecedented nature of the public health policy response to COVID-19, so too should the macroeconomic policies be understood and conducted. For example, the phrase “stimulus” may not be entirely appropriate now: Many people may not want to fly out of caution or be able to dine out because of legal decree. The goal of macroeconomic policy, at this stage, is not to “stimulate” them to do these things. Rather, at this stage, macroeconomic policy could be better described as maintenance and support, more a matter of insurance than stimulus. For example, enhanced unemployment benefits help maintain the income of workers temporarily laid off because of a change in demand in the sector where they had been employed.

Looking ahead, July 1 may provide an important checkpoint. At that point, there is a reasonable chance that public health needs will be reduced, allowing health authorities to ease the throttling down of U.S. economic activity. As of today, the situation remains fluid, and the views expressed here could easily change with events in the days and weeks ahead.

Notes and References

1 Any views expressed are my own and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Open Market Committee.

2 I take as a baseline for my analysis Ferguson et al. “Impact of Non-Pharmaceutical Interventions (NPIs) to Reduce COVID-19 Mortality and Healthcare Demand.” Imperial College, COVID-19 Report 9, March 16, 2020.

3 I recommend the following analogy: Suppose you are driving your car down the freeway at 70 mph, but then you encounter a construction zone. You have to slow down in the construction zone, perhaps quite significantly, work your way through the construction zone, and then resume your previous speed. There is nothing wrong with your car, but you nevertheless have to slow down.

4 I intend to update this value going forward as it becomes clearer which parts of the economy actually shut down and which parts do not.

5 Macroeconomic policy should seek to align household and business incentives with national health goals, not to work against those goals.

6 For example, economists often translate quarter-on-quarter growth rates in variables, such as GDP or consumption, into annual rates by (roughly) multiplying by four. In the current environment, one could see a quarter-on-quarter change in a variable of 50%. Annualized, this would be called a “200% decline.” Annualizing serves little use in the current environment.

7 I intend to refine this estimate going forward based on pandemic developments.

8 This may also be viewed as what macroeconomists call “home production,” that is, the movement of production from the market sector, where it is counted in GDP, to the home sector, where it is not counted in GDP. Famous and familiar examples of services that move back and forth between sectors are meals, which are sometimes eaten outside the home and sometimes produced in the home, as well as child care, which is sometimes provided at home and sometimes provided in a market setting.

Leave a Reply

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

13 thoughts on “Fed’s Bullard Calls For ‘Organized Shutdown’ Of US Economy Until July 1

  1. Financial markets and money are abstractions, you cant just shut down 50% of material goods and services production and “make everybody whole” like nothing happened. Bullard has officially gone off the deep end.

    1. “You cant just shut down 50% of material goods and services production and ‘make everybody whole’ like nothing happened”.

      Yes you can. You can commandeer material goods production by government decree in order to ensure what needs to get made gets made, and you keep necessary services provision online (like we’re already doing). And then you can just mail everybody checks.

      If this was a war, and another country had bombed us into a recession, we wouldn’t even be having this discussion. We would have instructed industries to make what needs to get made to go to war, and those whose livelihoods were destroyed by the initial bombing runs would be made whole with free money. And yet, somehow we don’t apply the same logic when it’s a virus. (“Somehow” = because most people lack the ability to extrapolate and don’t understand how money actually works)

      1. Taking your war analogy, in what war was everyone “made whole” there is always redistribution under the surface, no matter how many checks you mail. In WII we had price controls and inflation, the morons who bought the war bonds lost out big time. If being made whole is redistributing from creditors to lenders then yes everybody can be “made whole” but to me it sounds like the broken window fallacy.

    2. What is the share of workforce which is physically engaged into the goods production in the US? 5% of the total workforce maybe.
      I guess at least 50% of workforce can be successively removed without any material damage to goods or services production. This will decrease overall density at the working places and hence decrease probability of infections

    3. Probability of infection can be reduced even for essential businesses. R&D can be postponed, project management, finances and planning sent home, manufacturing work in several shifts do minimize personal contacts at the working places.

    1. In an unconstrained scenario, 300MM population x 50% infection rate x 1% fatality rate = 1.5MM deaths, also say 15MM in ICU treatment, since that exceeds ICU capacity by many ten-folds, fatality rate will be higher. 2MM? 3MM?

      A NPAP (weird acronym) with the appropriate government action (involving $3-4TR) will not kill 1.5MM or even 0.15MM.

      1. The numbers I’ve seen from smart Epidemiologist friends is a death rate of 8% once medical care is over run. These same people say 1% is the probable morality rate with proper hospital care.

  2. Rather than starting with the consumer “economy and cutting it down by some stupid arbitrary number, the necessary economy should be built up from zero. We need power generation. All of it. Less than full will kill people. We need food. Much of that is not easily sent in the mail. Keep the food coming. We need as much health care as we can get. Look at what we have to have and build from there. Don’t take half of everything. That’s the kind of advice you get from a stupid economist. Enough of these guys.

  3. LOL. Somehow, Jim Bullard’s blog posts always end up being extremely controversial. This one is inherently controversial, of course, but I swear, Jim could write a blog post about why he likes vanilla ice cream and suddenly, 99% of people would be staunch chocolate supporters.

  4. This is what leadership looks like. One could be forgiven for forgetting. We are indeed in a war and we should treat it that way with serious planning. Good on him!

NEWSROOM crewneck & prints